Page:Nixing the Fix.pdf/16

From Wikisource
Jump to navigation Jump to search
This page has been proofread, but needs to be validated.

aftermarket constitutes a relevant product market separate from the market for the sale of the product.[1] If a hypothetical monopolist of an aftermarket (that is not a monopolist in the market for the product) could profitably raise prices above the competitive level by at least a small but significant and non-transitory amount, then competition from other aftermarket firms is not sufficient to prevent anticompetitive behavior in the aftermarket. Thus, it is sometimes appropriate to analyze competition in a separate relevant market comprising the aftermarket.

But in many situations, application of general principles of market definition leads to a conclusion that a relevant market is not limited to the product of a single manufacturer, which is consistent with the Supreme Court’s discussion of the issue. Rather, relevant product markets typically include the products of multiple manufacturers.[2] In a broader market, a single manufacturer’s market share may not be sufficient to establish monopoly power in the relevant market.

Anticompetitive conduct by a monopolist can take many forms.[3] Examples of potentially anticompetitive conduct described elsewhere as undermining competition from non-OEMs include refusals to deal, exclusive dealing, exclusionary design, and aggressive assertion of patent rights.[4] Conduct that can harm competition may fit into one or more categories,[5] but the underlying inquiry is whether the conduct harms consumers.[6]

While the Supreme Court recognizes that a monopolist’s refusal to deal with its rivals under narrowly circumscribed circumstances may constitute exclusionary conduct supporting a violation of Section 2,[7] the Court has cautioned against imposing antitrust liability on firms that would require them to do business with other companies, including rivals or potential rivals.[8]


  1. A relevant market includes all products “reasonably interchangeable by consumers for the same purposes.” United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 395 (1956). The Supreme Court has defined monopoly power in a relevant market as “the power to control prices or exclude competition,” which can be shown through direct evidence or inferred where the defendant has a predominant share of a properly defined relevant market that is protected by entry barriers. See, e.g., United States v. Dentsply Int’l, Inc., 399 F.3d 181, 187 (3d Cir. 2005); Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 51.
  2. See, e.g., Town Sound & Custom Tops, Inc. v. Chrysler Motors, 959 F.2d. 468, 487–94 (3d Cir. 1992).
  3. The FTC has several pending cases challenging a variety of exclusionary conduct to maintain a monopoly in violation of the antitrust laws. See, e.g., FTC v. Surescripts, No. 19-1080 (D.D.C.) (complaint filed Apr. 17, 2019) (https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/cases/surescripts_redacted_complaint_4-24-19.pdf); FTC et al. v. Vyera Pharmaceuticals, LLC et al., No. 20-706 (S.D.N.Y) (complaint filed Jan. 27, 2020; amended complaint filed Apr. 14, 2020) (https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/cases/161_0001_vyera_amended_complaint.pdf); FTC v. Facebook, No. 1:20-cv-03590 (D.D.C.) (complaint filed Dec. 9, 2020) (https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/cases/051_2021.01.21_revised_partially_redacted_complaint.pdf); FTC v. Endo Pharmaceuticals et al., No. 1:21-cv-00217 (D.D.C.) (complaint filed Jan. 25, 2021) (https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/cases/redacted_complaint_0.pdf).
  4. See supra Section II and infra Section IV.
  5. Trinko, 540 U.S. at 414 (“the means of illicit exclusion, like the means of legitimate competition, are myriad.”) (internal quotes omitted).
  6. Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 58. See also Nynex Corp. v. Discon, Inc., 525 U.S. 128, 135 (1998) (plaintiffs “must allege and prove harm, not just to a single competitor, but to the competitive process, i.e., to competition itself.”).
  7. Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 601–11 (1985); Otter Tail Power Co. v. United States, 410 U.S. 366, 378 (1973).
  8. Trinko, 540 U.S. at 400–11 (2004) (such limited exceptions reside “at or near the outer boundary of § 2 liability.”). See also United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300, 307 (1919).

15